POSTWAR DEVELOPMENT

from: http://www.1upinfo.com/country-guide-study/japan/japan170.html

please click above for more details


After the end of World War II, Japan's economy was in a shambles, and its
international economic relations were almost completely disrupted. Initially,
imports were limited to essential food and raw materials, mostly financed by
economic assistance from the United States. Because of extreme domestic
shortages, exports did not begin to recover until the Korean War (1950-53),
when special procurement by United States armed forces created boom
conditions in indigenous industries. By 1954 economic recovery and
rehabilitation were essentially complete. For much of the 1950s, however,
Japan had difficulty exporting as much as it imported, leading to chronic trade
and current account deficits. Keeping these deficits under control, so that Japan
would not be forced to devalue its currency under the Bretton Woods System
(see Glossary) of fixed exchange rates that prevailed at the time, was a
primary concern of government officials. Stiff quotas and tariffs on imports were
part of the policy response. By 1960 Japan accounted for 3.6 percent of all
exports of noncommunist countries.


During the 1960s, the dollar value of exports grew at an average annual rate of
16.9 percent, more than 75 percent faster than the average rate of all
noncommunist countries. By 1970 exports had risen to nearly 6.9 percent of all
noncommunist-world exports. The rapid productivity growth in manufacturing
industries made Japanese products more competitive in world markets at the
fixed exchange rate for the yen (for value of the yen--see Glossary) during the
decade, and the chronic deficits that the nation faced in the 1950s had
disappeared by the middle of the 1970s. International pressure to dismantle
quota and tariff barriers mounted, and Japan began moving in this direction.
The 1970s brought major, wrenching changes for Japan's external relations.
The decade began with the end of the fixed exchange rate for the yen (a
change brought about mainly by rapidly rising Japanese trade and current
account surpluses) and with a strong rise in the value of the yen under the new
system of floating rates. Japan also faced sharply higher bills for imports of
energy and other raw materials. The new exchange rates and the rise in raw
material prices meant that the surpluses of the decade's beginning were lost,
and large trade deficits followed in the wake of the oil price shocks of 1973 and
1979. Expanding the country's exports remained a priority in the face of these
raw material supply shocks, and during the decade exports continued to
expand at a high annual average rate of 21 percent (see Balance of
Merchandise Trade , this ch.).


Most of the concerns of the 1970s diminished in the 1980s. Oil and other raw
material prices fell dramatically, and Japan's trade deficits turned quickly to
enormous trade surpluses by the middle of the decade. In response to these
surpluses, the value of the yen rose against that of other currencies in the last
half of the decade, but the surpluses proved surprisingly resilient to this
change. The large surpluses, combined with foreign perceptions that Japan's
import markets were still relatively closed, exacerbated tension between Japan
and a number of its principal trading partners, especially the United States. A
rapid increase in imports of manufactured goods after 1987 eased some of
these tensions, but as the decade ended, friction still continued.


Through most of the postwar period, foreign investment was not a significant
part of Japan's external economic relations. Both domestic and foreign
investments were carefully controlled by government regulations, which kept the
investment flows small. These controls applied to direct investment in the
creation of subsidiaries under the control of a parent company, portfolio
investment, and lending. Controls were motivated by the desire to prevent
foreigners (mainly Americans) from gaining ownership of the economy when
Japan was in a weak position after World War II, and by concerns over the
balance of payments deficits (see Capital Flows , this ch.). Beginning in the late
1960s, these controls were gradually loosened, and the process of deregulation
accelerated and continued throughout the 1980s. The result was a dramatic
increase in capital movements, with the biggest change occurring in
outflows--investments by Japanese in other countries. By the end of the 1980s,
Japan had become a major international investor. Because the country was a
newcomer to the world of overseas investment, this development led to new
forms of tension with other countries, including criticism of highly visible
Japanese acquisitions in the United States and elsewhere.

 

See also by the same author:

Japan's postwar economic miracle (1950-1990)

Written by Maciamo on 16 May 2004

http://www.jref.com/society/japan_postwar_economic_miracle.shtml

In 1951, Japan's GNP was US$14,2 billion, half of West Germany, 3x less than Britain, and a mere 4,2% of the US economy. By 1970, Japan had overtaken all European economies, and represented over 20% of the US's GNP. In 1975, it was double of the UK's, and 1980, it reached US$1040 billion, roughly 40% of the US's.

We have seen what favourable conditions have prompted the economic boom following the American occupation. But what are the factors that allowed the Japanese economy to sustain its exceptional growth during the three decades from 1950 to the late 1980's ?

First of all, Japan benefited from the American military protection, which spared the government from high defense spendings. The same happened in West Germany, and both nations experienced the most formidable economic growth in the postwar era. But whereas West Germany's GNP increased 28,5x between 1951 and 1980 - compared to 18,7x for France, 12,7x for Britain and only 8x for the USA, Japan's increased 73x !

Their are obvious reasons for which we should minimize this number at first. The yen was intentionally set to a very low rate in the 1950's, and was worth 3x to 4x more in 1980's. At equal exchange rate to the US$, the Japanese economy didn't grow 9x faster but less than 3x. The second reason is that Japan was completely destroyed in 1945, its cities flattened and industry annihilated, while the US did not suffer any damages on their home land and had nothing to rebuild. It thus took Japan many years to recover its prewar level. Had the country ended the war intact, the economic "miracle" would not have happened. The same goes for Germany, which GNP stood at 68% of the UK's in 1951, while it had obviously been superior to it during its WWII peak.

Coredo, Nihombashi, Tokyo

However, the Japanese economy continued to grow steadily, quintupling its size every decade.

But the Japanese economic miracle didn't owe only to having to reconstruct the country and mobilising the entirety of the war's military spending, installations and energy into business. Although the economy was based on the American liberal system, the government boosted business by providing low interest loans to sectors designed for growth, and organized the economy to facilitate development as much as possible. For example, the MITI (Ministry of International Trade and Industry) pressured iron and steel producers to acquire the licence rights of a new Austrian oxygen furnace together, thus sharing the costs and benefits, while the logic of Anglo-saxon free-market would have had each company obtain the licence individually at much higher expenditure.

Japanese enterprises borrowed massively from banks, which drew their funds from high households savings. Inflation made it easy for them to pay them back without difficulty - until the bubble burst in 1990, which left the banks with innumerable bad loans and brought many to bankruptcy or need of financial support from the state.

 

And, from: http://www.iun.edu/~hisdcl/h207_2002/jecontakeoff.htm

Japanese economic takeoff after 1945

Note: Unless specified, the paragraphs with citations are almost completely taken from the books/articles cited. If you need to use the information here for your paper, please cite the authors cited in the paragraphs.

    In September 1945, Japan had nearly 3 million war dead and the loss of a quarter of the national wealth.   How did Japan become the second largest economy in the world in the 1980s? Postwar Japanese economic takeoff was due to a variety of factors that had to do with American policies toward Japan, the international market, social mobilization, existent industrial capacities and experience, and government policies and expertise, among other things.  

1. Wartime experience:

    Between 1937 and 1945, during the war years, Japanese economy received rapid development. Production indices showed increases of 24 percent in manufacturing, 46 percent in steel, 70 percent in nonferrous metals, and 252 percent in machinery. Much of the increasingly militarized economy was diverse and sophisticated in ways that facilitated conversion to peacetime activity.   On the automobile industry, for instance, of the 11 major auto manufacturers in postwar Japan, ten came out of the war years: only Honda is a pure product of the postwar period.   Three of the ten: Toyota, Nissan, and Isuzu, prospered as the primary producers of trucks for the military after legislation passed in 1936 had driven Ford and General Motors out of the Japanese market.   Other corporate giants on the postwar scene gained comparable competitive advantage during the war years.   Normura Securities, which is now the second wealthiest corporation in Japan after Toyota, was founded in 1925 as a firm specializing in bonds.   Its great breakthrough as a securities firm, however, came through expansion into stocks in 1938 and investment trust operations in 1941.   Hitachi, Japan's largest manufacturer of electrical equipment, was established in 1910 but emerged as a comprehensive vertically integrated producer of electric machinery in the 1930s as part of the Ayukawa conglomerate that also included Nissan.   Similarly, Toshiba, which ranks second after Hitachi in electric products, dates back to 1904 but only became a comprehensive manufacturer of electric goods following a merger carried out in 1939 under the military campaign to consolidate and rationalize production.   Whole sectors were able to take off in the postwar period by building on advances made during the war. (this paragraph is based on John Dower, 1992, pp.54-55).

    After the war was over, many of the wartime companies and much of the technology used during the war were converted to peaceful economic development. Japanese private companies expanded quickly and fearlessly.   They borrowed massive amounts from banks and took on large debts. The private companies developed rapidly, against the conservative advice of the government that they merge so as to compete more effectively against Detroit's Big Three.   Instead, Toyota, Nissan, Isuzu, Toyo Kogyo (Mazda), and Mitsubishi all decided to produce full lines.   An upstart motorcycle company founded by Honda Soichiro defied bureaucratic warnings and entered the auto market in 1963 with great long run success.   In 1953, two young mavericks, Morita Akio and Ibuka Masaru, struggled for months with reluctant state officials before winning permission to purchase a license to make transistors.   Beginning with the radio in the 1950s, their infant company, Sony, soon emerged as the global leader in quality an innovation in consumer electronics goods. (Gordon, 248-49)

    Nationalism and the desire to catch up with the West persisted after WWII, but now the efforts were focused on economic and industrial goals.   For example, machine gun factories were converted to make sewing machines; optical weapons factories now produced cameras and binoculars.(Pyle, p.242)

    The great devastation of the Japanese economy during the war and the need to rebuild it from scratch often led to the introduction of new technology and new management styles, which gave these companies a chance to update and upgrade themselves.   Their changes were met with a friendly international environment of free trade, cheap technology and cheap raw materials. During the Cold War years, Japan was the client and friend of the advanced U.S. economy and Japanese markets were allowed to be closed while the American market was open to Japanese goods.

2. U.S. policies toward Japan after 1947

      During the Cold War, strategic interests led the U.S. to allow Japan to export to the US while protecting its domestic market, enabling the formation of cartels and non-market driven factors in Japanese economy, and the development of an asymmetrical trade relationship with the U.S.   The export-driven economy that Japan consequently developed also benefited enormously from an international market of low tariffs (by joining the GATT, forerunner of WTO), low prices of oil and other raw materials needed for industrial development.

    Because Article 9 of the Japanese constitution forbids Japan from rearmament, Japan has lived under the umbrella of U.S. military protection, spending only 1 per cent of their GNP on the military's defensive abilities (which is a huge sum of money as the Japanese economy grew to be the second largest in the world), which, percentage wise, helped save the Japanese much money if they were militarily on their own.

2. The welfare society in Japan

    In Japan, a welfare society rather than welfare state exists, characterized by total employment, including cartels of small and medium sized companies to prevent them from bankruptcy in order to maintain total employment.

    The welfare society and total employment enabled the Japanese state to devote much of the money it would have spent on welfare to industrial development, in the form of bank loans.

    The birth of the welfare society:

        During the American occupation:1946-49, Japanese economy was sustained by $500 million annually from the US.   Despite this help, because of wartime devastation, Japanese economy was in shambles.

        In reaction, the American occupational forces invited the Detroit banker Dodge to balance Japanese economy, who introduced the Dodge Plan (1949): balance budget, reduce inflation, repay Japanese government debts. Fix exchange rate ($1=360 yen). (compared with $1=110 yen today)

        That this exchange rate made Japanese yen too expensive shows the high inflation going on in Japan before 1949.

        Reaction to the Dodge Plan: massive laying off of workers and economic recession, because Japanese goods became less competitive in the international market (too expensive) (Dodge hoped that after the initial pain, Japanese economy would start steady development later on).

        In reaction: state bank loans to private companies to prevent them from bankruptcy. In the 1950s, major concern of Japanese economy was capital accumulation and export promotion; also medium sized companies protested against tax increases.   These concerns prevented the formation of a welfare state because that would require tax increases.   Instead, the state promoted a welfare society through legislation.   The welfare society, through maintaining near total employment via liberal government loans to private companies, dispensed with the need for unemployment benefits.   Retirement pensions came largely from personal savings and company compensation, rather than benefits from the state.

        The welfare society saved Japanese government much money, which was liberally loaned to companies and guaranteed a secure supply of funding to many companies, leading some to competition and technological innovation. (but it also prevented some companies from upgrading themselves because of guaranteed funding, so it was a two sided story).

        Under the welfare society, limited unemployment benefits do exist, but they are provided by the private companies. The unemployment insurance premiums are borne by workers and employers on a fifty-fifty basis. The government pays only a partial sum of the management and operation costs--14 percent of the cost for unemployment insurance and the other services concerning unemployment is covered directly out of the national treasury account. The wage withholding is, in principle, set at 1.1 percent of the total annual salary. However, the actual rate of contribution to these schemes was lowered to 0.9 percent in fiscal 1992, and has been at 0.8 percent since fiscal 1993. Unemployment benefits were 60 percent to 80 percent of the wage before becoming unemployed for a period of 90 to 300 days, which was extended to 330 days after 2001. Conditions vary depending on age and length of time contributing to the system. The larger private companies were also responsible for subsidized housing, health benefits, retirement pension and other benefits for recreational activities in a package called lifetime employment, practiced after 1960. All these, naturally add to the cost of big corporations, which then pass the cost on to the consumers in the form of higher prices.

3. Financing the Japanese economy and cooperation between the state and businesses

    In the years from 1950 on, Japanese leaders in the bureaucracy and ruling political party, working in tandem with corporate executives, actively sought to manage and develop the economy. Over the 23 years from 1950 to 1973, Japan's gross national product (GNP; the total value of goods and services produced in a year) expanded by an average annual rate of more than 10 per cent with only a few minor downturns.   There was also a high rate of investment in technology. (Gordon, 246) Japan developed an export-oriented economy: much of what it manufactured would be sold abroad and the foreign currency they made would be invested in the purchase of technology, management, raw materials and energy sources for its further industrial development.   Japan is a country with few raw materials for industrial development and non known oil reserves except for recent limited offshore discoveries.   Today over 70 percent of manufactured goods from Japan are exported abroad.   When this export driven economy first started in the 1950s, Japan had a favorable international environment: The United States led in negotiating a more open trading system through treaties such as the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (GATT, predecessor to today's WTO, World Trade Organization).   Cheap and reliable energy supplies in the form of oil from the Middle East and elsewhere fueled industrial expansion at relatively low costs.   Relatively affordable licensing agreements also gave Japanese companies open access to a host of new technologies from transistors to steel furnaces.

    A. Government regulation in the form of loans:

    Private banks, as well as public institutions such as the   Industrial Development Bank, drew on individual savings to channel capital to businesses.   In the early years of Japanese economic development from the 1950s to 1960s,   1/3 of the bank loans came from private savings.   The average household saved under 10 per cent of its income in the early 1950s, but savings rate soared steadily as the economy grew and reached 15 percent by 1960 and topped 20 percent by 1970.   Households have continued to save in excess of 20 percent since then.   These funds, deposited in savings accounts of commercial banks or in the government run postal savings system, made up a vast pool of capital available for investment in industry. (Gordon, 246) There has been such extensive government regulation of Japanese industry that Japanese capitalism is sometimes called "brokered capitalism" to refer to the extensive role the state plays in it.   Of all government ministries, perhaps MITI has been the most instrumental.   MITI and the Ministry of Finance encouraged the rationalization of firms and industries and guided the structural transformation of the economy.   MITI stimulated the movement of capital and labor out of declining industries such as coal and textiles and into promising new industries with high growth potential--first into electronics, steel, petrochemicals, and automobiles, and later into computers, semiconductors, and biotechnology. (Pyle, 247)

    Since MITI achieved most of its goals with the distribution of loans, where did the money come from? As mentioned above, a sizable amount of money came from personal savings, which was then channeled to economic development. The Ministry of Finance and MITI established the Japan Development Bank in 1951 with access to a huge investment pool known as the Fiscal Investment and Loan Plan (FLIP), which comprised the nation's savings in the postal savings system, a favorite place for individuals to put their money in because their accounts were tax exempt.   FLIP thus amassed the savings four times the size of the world's largest commercial bank.   It became a powerful policy tool which MITI used to provide low-cost capital to industries it favored for long term growth.   The Ministry of Finance was ensuring the availability of capital.   It put restrictions on the inflow or outflow of capital.   It could ration and guide the flow of capital to large firms in industries such as steel, shipbuilding, automobiles, electronics and chemicals that were adopting new technology and were central to increasing productivity and exports.   They also used tariffs, direct and indirect subsidies to key industries, for development. (Pyle, 247-48)

    Where else does the money come from for MITI and the Ministry of Finance? Another important reason to explain the money for economic growth, besides the small percentage of Japan's GDP on military spending (1%), has been the minimum the government spent on welfare.   Instead of building a welfare state, the government has encouraged the Japanese to become a welfare society--through total employment, in order to reduce or eliminate the need for the state to spend on unemployment benefits.   Although retirement pension did exist for some workers in large companies, it was primarily the result of contributions of the company and the workers, and state contribution was minimal.   Again, like unemployment benefits, pensions were paid out by individual employees and their companies on a 50/50 matching basis. Unlike the U.S. social security system, the Japanese state was involved in the process only in entrusting the money from both sides to a designated company for investment and payment upon the employees' retirement based on an agreed upon sum of annuity at the beginning of the employees' employment. This system also encouraged employees to stay in the same company for life in order to get the amount of pension promised at the beginning. The money the Japanese state saved from public spending was invested in the economy in the form of liberal bank loans from the Bank of Japan to the citibanks and other regional banks that boosted competition and technological innovations. (Gao, 2001)

    According to John Dower, the Japanese bureaucratic control of economy through the many banks could trace its origin again to the war.   Before 1927, there were about 1,400 ordinary commercial banks in Japan.   That number steadily dropped so that by 1945, by mergers and absorptions, it was 61.   And there has been little change since.   The so called "city banks" which are really national banks, that stand at the hub of the postwar enterprise groups were in most instances greatly strengthened by critical legislation introduced between 1942 and 1944, which designated a certain number of "authorized financial institutions" to receive special support from the government and Bank of Japan in providing the great bulk of loans to over 600 major producers of strategic war materials.   Thus, in 1931 the ratio of direct (equity, meaning stocks issued to the public or to some other private companies) to indirect (bank loan) financing of industry was roughly 9:1.   By 1935, it was 7:3, and by 1945, as in the mid 1960s, it was 1:9 (meaning for every dollar a company got from issuing tocks, it got nine dollars from bank loans). (Dower,1992, pp.57-58) After the war, because of indirect U.S. rule during the American occupation, the Japanese bureaucratic structure remained largely intact, and the Japanese government used some major banks to issue loans and direct economic development.

    B. Steps to avoid competition: monopolies (zaibatsu) and the Keiretsu

    During the American occupation, one of the decisions MacArthur made to liberalize Japan was to abolish the monopolies (zaibatsu).   Because of the onset of the Cold War and the Korean War, the anti-monopoly stance was not upheld by the Americans to give the Japanese businesses a chance to compete more aggressively internationally.   This opportunity was seized upon by the Japanese government.   On Sept.1, 1953, the Diet amended the Anti-Monopoly Law so as to relax the Occupation-imposed restrictions on cartels, interlocking directorates, and mergers.   To maximize the efficient use of resources, MITI preferred to have competition limited to a small number of very large corporations.   The Fair Trade Commission's authority to prevent restraint of trade was constantly under attack from MITI.   In one of the better documented cases of collusive behavior that resulted from the changed rules, six Japanese firms manufacturing televisions joined forces, forming a market stabilization group in 1956 to control the domestic price of televisions. They maintained a high price level in the domestic market while government tariff policy kept the market closed to foreign producers.   With high profit margins and an ensured market at home, the industry turned to exports, especially to the US market.   Through below-cost exports to the US market, the Japanese firms were able to drive most of their US competitors out of business.   The Japanese government spurred and shaped the development of the television industry through preferential credit allocation via large banks, lax antitrust enforcement, condoning of de facto recession cartels, MITI guided investment coordination, and various forms of non-tariff barriers. (Pyle, 248)

    Besides sustaining monopolies to some extent, the Japanese government also condoned the building of a more flexible business alliance of different companies, either horizontally or vertically, called the keiretsu.   Six great enterprise groups--Mitsui, Mitsubishi, Sumitomo, Fuyo, Dai-ichi Kangyo, and Sanwa--were organized horizontally.   That is, each "horizontal keiretsu" comprised several dozen members including a main bank, large financial institutions, the largest manufacturing firms, and a large general trading company.   Within each group, members held each other's shares.   They had interlocking directorates and engaged in intragroup financing and joint R&D ventures.   These horizontal keiretsu helped to provide long-term stability, efficiency, reduced risk, and mutual support.   There were also giant vertical keiretsu organized in the automobile, electronic, and other industries (Nissan, Toyota, Hitachi, Matsushita, Sony, etc.).   They served to organize huge numbers of subcontractors and suppliers of services.   The vertical keiretsu provided efficient, long term reciprocal benefits for a parent company and its suppliers, including coordination of planning and investment, sharing of technology and information, control of quality and delivery, and flexibility throughout the business cycles. Finally, the distribution keiretsu allowed manufacturers to control the mass marketing of products.   These networks allowed manufacturers to prevent price competition among retailers, to maintain high profit margins in the domestic market, and so to permit cutthroat competition in the international market.   In other words, they become an effective means to force Japanese consumers to subsidize the international competitiveness of large manufacturing firms.(Pyle, 250)

    The following is an example of a keiretsu:

    Reciprocal shareholding of Mitsubishi Bank (1974)

    Top ten companies owned by Mitsubishi Bank                                                                         per cent of shares

    Mitsubishi Heavy Industry                                                      5.7

    New Japan Steel                                                                   1.4

    Mitsubishi Trading Company                                                 7.8          

    Asahi Hyaline                                                                        7.6

    Mitsubishi Chemical                                                              5.6

    Mitsubishi Motors                                                                  3.3

    Mitsubishi Real Estate                                                           3.9

    Tokyo Marine and Fire Insurance                                         5.7

    Kikki Japan Railway                                                            3.5

    Japan Vessel                                                                        4.3

    Top ten owners of Mitsubishi Bank

    Meiji Life Insurance                                                             5.9

    Tokyo Marine and Fire Insurance                                        4.7

    Daiichi Life Insurance                                                          3.6

    Mitsubishi Heavy Industry                                                   3.2

    Japan Life Insurance                                                             3.2

    Asahi Hyaline                                                                      2

    Mitsubishi Trading Company                                               2

    Mitsubishi Motors                                                                1.4

    New Japan Steel                                                                 1.3

    Mitsubishi Trust Bank                                                          1.3

    Source: Hiroshi Okumura.   1975.   Hojin Shibonshugi no kozo (The structure of cooperative capitalism.)   Tokyo: Nihon Hyoronsha.   From Bai Gao, Japan's Economic Dilemma: The Institutional Origins of Prosperity and Stagnation.   New York & Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001, p.94.

4. labor unions, part time workers, and small companies.

    Local nature of labor unions

        In Japan, trade unions, in the 1940s and 50s, were very militant, so much so that the Japanese government and big businesses decided to negotiate with them via Confucian values of trust and reciprocity.   Unionized workers were promised life time employment in exchange for relatively speaking low salaries.   This only applied to big companies.   In small ones, workers did not have either job security or high salary.   This mutual understanding, reached between unions and the management after a tremendous coal miners' strike in 1960, allowed unions to negotiate with companies on a company basis instead of industry wide. It led to many company based unions and dedication to work with the reward of lifetime employment, which, together with numerous on job trainings, also contributed to postwar Japanese takeoff.   The trade unions were more concerned about job security than consumer rights of the union members.

    Part time workers

        Although the welfare society maintained a total employment philosophy, it included many part-time workers who did not enjoy workplace benefits and had very low pay, and who were largely women.   These people often worked for small companies that did not provide benefits such as lifetime employment as the big companies started to do after 1960, and unemployment did happen in these small companies.   Quite a percentage of the work of the big companies, such as Toyota and Sony, were contracted to these small companies which helped to reduce costs and add to the profit margin of the products.

5. Social mobilization of the Japanese: sacrifice for the nation's place in international economy

    Ultimately it was the Japanese consumers who bore the brunt of shouldering the cost of Japanese companies' competition abroad, in the form of high cost of consumer goods.   After the war, they were taught to redirect their devotion to the nation from its military expansion to economic expansion.   They were constantly exhorted that they were a homogeneous people and superior to all other Asians, and superior even to the whites.   To establish their national position in the postwar world, they should not be very concerned about individual well being, thus should not mind the high cost they have to pay for consumer goods that cost less abroad.   It is the same kind of mentality that prevented the Japanese from talking about their worries and pressure and ethnic/religious differences that Norma Field discusses in her In the Realm of A Dying Emperor, while worries, anger, and frustration still pop up unexpectedly, often from the periphery instead of mainstream Japanese society.

 

The following is a bibliography of books used for this presentation.

Bibliography:

Dower, John.   "The Useful War," in Carol Gluck and Stephen Graubard, eds., Showa: The Japan of   Hirohito.   New York & London: W.W.Norton, 1992.

Gao, Bai.   Japan's Economic Dilemma: The Institutional Origins of Prosperity and Stagnation.   New York & Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001

Gordon, Andrew.   A Modern History of Japan: From Tokugawa Times to the Present.   New York & Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003.

Pyle, Kenneth.   The Making of Modern Japan, 2nd ed.   Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath, 1996.